Economics is concerned with marginal costs and benefits. Since our resources are scarce, we must decide the amount of pollution we are willing to live with. In order to have a pollution-free world, we would have to give up many other things. Money spent to clean up pollution would not be spent on education, roads, crime prevention, public health programs and so on. The government usually provides for education, roads, etc. It does so because these are things our society considers very important but things that might not be provided for by private enterprise. Economists call these items market failures and have identified several types of market failures.
MARKET FAILURE: THE FAILURE OF COMPETITIONOne type of market failure is a monopoly where there is a failure of competition. One recent example is Microsoft. Microsoft's rivals in the computer software industry showed that Microsoft had attempted to develop its dominant position in operating systems software (such as Windows) to gain a dishonest advantage and so create a monopoly in operating systems. Microsoft also created a monopoly in the sales of its applications software (like Microsoft Word).
MARKET FAILURE: PUBLIC GOODSA public good is a good that is provided in the same amount to all consumers if provided at all. A pure public good is non-excludable and non-rival. Once provided it is impossible to prevent agents from consuming it but one agent’s consumption doesn’t reduce the amount available to other agents. Some examples are public TV, World Service Radio, air, etc. A free-for-all public good is non-excludable and rival. It is impossible to prevent agents from using it and one agent’s consumption does reduce the amount available to other agents. Some examples are roads, fish, public beaches, etc. Since public goods are non-excludable, they represent a type of market failure.
MARKET FAILURE: THE TRAGEDY OF THE COMMONSIn 1832, William Forster Lloyd observed the devastation of common pastures and the puny and stunted draft animals that grazed on them. Immigrants to New England in the 17th century formed villages in which they had privately owned homesteads and gardens, but they also set aside community-owned pastures, called commons, where all villagers' livestock could graze. Settlers had an incentive to avoid overusing their own private land, so it would remain productive in the future. However, the self-interested stewardship of private land did not extend to the commons. As a result, the commons were overgrazed and degenerated to the point that they were no longer able to support villagers' livestock. In 1968, Garrett Hardin created the economic term tragedy of the commons --.the failure of private incentives to provide adequate maintenance of public resources. The commons refers to any resource shared by a group of people. As the population grows, greed runs rampant and the commons collapses. The tragedy of the commons is one of the most important topics in the human-earth relationship. Many resources – clean air, biodiversity, fresh water – are available to many people, and when resources are shared and limited (even if potentially renewable), those resources are often exploited. This is because the benefit to one person of using more of the resource outweighs the cost to that one person of the resource's overuse. Each person looks out for his own interests and succumbs to the logic that "If I don't use the resource, then someone else will. I might as well get the benefit." The plight of the commons in Lloyd's day is similar to a number of contemporary examples of the tragedy of the commons: the depletion of fish stocks in international waters, industrial air pollution, congestion on urban highways and the rise of resistant diseases due to the careless use of antibiotics, just to name a few. The problem in all tragedy of the commons cases is directly related to the lack of clearly established property rights (a type of market failure). Learning to overcome our natural tendency to overuse common resources is one of the most significant challenges we face in working to improve our physical environment.
|
factory choices |
factory profit |
fishermen profit |
total profit |
no filter no treatment |
$500 |
$100 |
$600 |
filter no treatment |
$300 |
$500 |
$800 |
no filter treatment |
$500 |
$200 |
$700 |
filter treatment |
$300 |
$300 |
$600 |
1. What if the factory is given the right to dump?
2. Which alternative seems to be the most advantageous to the fisherman?
3. How might a reasonable and equitable solution be achieved?
4. Which of the alternatives seem to be the most equitable?
5. What are the negative and positive externalities if property rights are assigned to the fishermen?
6. What are the negative and positive externalities if property rights are assigned to the factory?
7. What solutions apart, from Coase, could solve this problem?
The Coase and Pigouvian Theorems (PDF Presentation)
|